Market-Based Models for Land Development for the
Low/Moderate-Income Majority
Bruce Ferguson
Hybrid value
chains (see Ashoka, 2008 and Ferguson, 2008 in this issue of
Global Urban Development Magazine) provide a tool to
analyze, improve, and create affordable housing projects and
products. Nowhere is the need and opportunity greater than in
land development (Global Urban Development Magazine,
November 2007).
Virtually all net growth of 2.6 billion in world population
between now and 2050 is projected to occur in emerging-country
cities. The majority of these new households will earn low or
moderate incomes. In effect, relatively poor countries must
build the equivalent of a city of more than one million people
each week for the next 45 years (Cohen, 2005)! Rapid
rural-to-urban migration (particularly in South Asia and Africa,
where large majorities still live in rural areas) as well as
in-situ population growth have created this surge in urban
population. Although these households will earn incomes well
below those of affluent countries, the huge increase in
emerging-city populations will drive growth in the world economy
and demand for many products. From 2001 to 2007, emerging
economies grew at an average annual rate of over 6% compared to
2.5% in high-income advanced countries, and have resisted the
current “credit crunch” (as of July 2008) far better than
affluent nations. The importance of emerging nations in the
global economy will only increase in coming decades
Absent major change, the bulk of new residential land
development will occur informally without integration into
mainstream markets, at tremendous public and private cost.
Settling this wave of new urban residents far exceeds the
challenge of upgrading existing urban shantytowns containing one
billion people. Experts (Global Urban Development
Magazine, 2007; Freire, Lima, Cira, Ferguson, Kessides, Mota
and Motta, 2007; Ferguson, 2007; Buckley, 2005) and housing
developers agree that land presents the greatest constraint to
sheltering the low and moderate-income majority. Government
programs, however, typically result in boutique high-subsidy
projects incapable of reaching a scale commensurate to this
challenge. New market-based approaches are essential to reach
the enormous necessary scope.
This paper first presents a hybrid value-chain framework with
particular attention to urban land development to provide a
systematic method for guiding private-sector initiative. It
then uses this framework to analyze and specify how to improve
two cases of market-based urban land development – one in
Pakistan with a nonprofit as the developer and one in El
Salvador where for-profit firms are the protagonists – based on
interviews and reports prepared for this study. This analysis
also helps identify the roles of private firms, the citizen
sector (variously called “nonprofits”, “NGOs”, and the “social
sector”), and government in achieving massive low-income land
development.
A hybrid
value chain approach to urban land development
Table 1 (distilled from Table 2 of Ferguson’s policy
introduction on the value chain framework to this issue of
Global Urban Development Magazine) lists the main steps of
the progressive housing process used by most families in
emerging countries, a set of overall criteria to assess
outcomes, and products and services for streamlining this
practice. The key to creating value and markets in affordable
housing is not only to lower the costs of each of these steps
but also, more importantly, to innovate and combine products and
services into new business models that address
larger segments of the problem – i.e. “value chains.”
Modern companies develop competitive advantage by vertically
integrating the sourcing, manufacturing, and delivery of
packages of products and services (Porter, 1985). Hence, these
firms are well suited to squeezing costs out of the progressive
housing process. However, they typically have little direct
access to poor communities, which they find dangerous and
difficult places in which to work, and to low-income people, who
usually do not trust them. Citizen-sector organizations that
work in these neighborhoods can perform an important function at
critical junctures in the value chain. As a result, the most
effective value chains are “hybrid” efforts that join modern
corporations with citizen-sector organizations.
A broad summary of the context of residential land
development in emerging countries cities serves to preface
application of this hybrid value-chain framework to specific
projects and products.
During the early phases of the great urban wave during the
1950s and 1960s, poor households migrating to cities from the
countryside could, with some frequency, find centrally located
low-cost parcels to invade. This land offered a low-cost
foothold near to the city center and jobs, which families could
turn into a valuable asset.
However, continuing urbanization has used up most land
vulnerable to invasion. As a result, most new low/moderate
income households now settle in illegal subdivisions on the
periphery and beyond, stretching over vast areas. In effect,
illegal subdivisions have become the default mechanism for urban
land development. Typically, clandestine developers acquire
parcels, mark areas for dirt streets, divide the remaining area
into lots, and sell these raw lots to poor households. Most
emerging countries and cities have officially made such
unserviced land development illegal under their subdivision
codes. However, the bulk of these governments unofficially
allow or promote unserviced land development as the only viable
alternative for massive low-income settlement. Others lack the
enforcement mechanisms to control this phenomenon.
Table 1
Framework for
assessing and improving affordable housing projects and products
Steps in the progressive housing process |
Goods and services necessary to streamline process and reduce costs |
1. Acquisition and occupancy of a lot
a.
Physically occupy lot
b. Pay
for lot
c.
Starter infrastructure for occupation
d. Construct an initial makeshift shelter |
-
Formally-developed subdivisions with “starter”
services (e.g. collective water and a gravel road
network) located near trunk infrastructure lines
-
Low-cost norms and streamlined processing for
approval of subdivisions with “starter services”
(e.g. communal standpipes/wells or “tanker” water,
dirt roads, electricity) and progressive provision
of other infrastructure and services over a
predictable timeframe.
|
2.
Upgrading property tenure for security of occupation
a.
Maintain physical control of the lot
b.
Achieve secure tenure
c.
Full
legal title |
|
3.
Provision of basic infrastructure
a. Upgrading (e.g. road network, paving, drainage)
b. Adequate sanitation (improved pit latrines or sewerage)
|
-
Lobbying for and brokering infrastructure and
collective services from various levels of
government and private sector organizations.
-
Organizing the community to help maintain and pay
for installed infrastructure and collective services
(e.g. cleaning drains, operating community centers)
|
4.
Construction of the house structure
a.
Improve/ expand unit of owner occupant
b.
Add
accessory units and spaces for relatives and rental
income |
-
Packages of high quality building materials.
-
Technical assistance in design, budgeting, and
construction of houses
-
Market information on the type of home improvement
and upgrading of property tenure that increases home
values.
|
5.
Finance of steps in progressive housing process
a. Household savings vehicles
b. Small serial short-term credit for:
-purchase of lot
-infrastructure provision and connection
-expansion and improvement of structure |
-
Organizing groups of households to
save for home upgrading
and to demonstrate creditworthiness.
-
Saving vehicles that create discipline
and give a positive real interest rate
-
A
range of credit including: microfinance; supplier
and consumer
credit from developers and building materials
retailers; and small mortgage loans; not only for
building materials but also for specialized
technical labor.
|
6.
Building community institutions to combat insecurity
a.
Formation of neighborhood groups
b. Local and international NGOs support neighborhood groups
c.
Neighborhood groups and NGOs partner with public and
private sector to increase security |
-
Organizing community associations and funding
sources to operate them.
-
Developing women's networks to market goods and
services
-
Community centers with daycare and youth facilities
-
Agreements with the police and other authorities
that enhance security
-
Investment in street lighting and local police
stations
|
Overall characteristics |
Outcome measurement/description |
1.
Sustainability
a. Scale
b. Financial
c. Political
d. Environmental |
-
Number of units produced relative to demand (new
household formation)
-
Positive net return
-
Reliance on government action and resources, and
dependability of this public support
-
Impact on households’ health and the natural
environment
|
2.
Location relative to existing infrastructure,
services, and jobs |
-
Distance from trunk infrastructure, services, and
jobs
|
3.
Targeting/affordability |
-
Share of project/product that serves low-income
households
|
In this context, creating value chains for land development
involves making clandestine subdivisions legal through
regulating and supporting their development in order to reduce
the cost and length of this process. The following sections
summarize two in-depth case studies of market-based low-income
urban land development, and then apply this hybrid value-chain
framework to rate and specify how to improve them. The full
versions of these case studies are available on Ashoka’s website
at www.ashoka.org.
The
progressive subdivision market in El Salvador
Progressive subdivisions started in the 1960s in the
municipalities of the capitol, San Salvador (Barraza, 2007;
Souza, 2001), and now serve 60% of new low-income households
throughout the country, with sales of 5,000 to 8,000 lots per
year.
Roughly 70 firms belong to the Association of Land Developers
of El Salvador, and are active in this market. The four largest
firms (Argoz, Proyectos Dinamicos, Lotiversa, and Ivan) operate
on a national scale and account for one-half of new lot
production (Barraza, 2007; Souza, 2001).
Typically (80% of projects), firms approach landowners of
parcels near or on major roads on the urban periphery and in
semi-rural zones, and offer to form partnerships to subdivide
this land. The firm commits to execute and administer the
subdivision, and pass on 60% to 75% of payments from individual
households to the landowner.
The developer sets aside 35% of the parcel for streets,
communal infrastructure, and, higher-end projects, green space,
and then divides up the remaining 65% into 20 to 35 lots of 150
square meters (in suburban zones) to 250 square meters (in
semirural zones). The firm levels and prepares the terrain,
demarcates lots and roads, compacts dirt roads, and, for
higher-end projects, drills communal wells and leaves space for
parks. Electricity companies make individual households
connections in parallel with the subdivision.
Marketing usually consists of putting a billboard at the
front of the parcel advertising lots for sale with a telephone
number. Developers establish local offices to receive monthly
payments and also make arrangements with banks to receive these
monies on their behalf. Low-income people buy the great bulk
of these lots. In addition, significant sales now come from
the Salvadoran community in the US seeking to build a home to
retire to their native country and investors.
Developers use a rental contract with promise of sale (contrato
de arrendamiento con promesa de venta; hereafter, called a
“rent-to-own contract”) for this purpose. This rent- to-own
contract stipulates a monthly payment of US $15 to $70 per month
for 8 to 12 years, representing an affordable 15%-20% of income
of low and moderate-income households earning US$175-$350 per
month. This legal vehicle maintains ownership of the lot with
the developer/landowner partnership until the last monthly
payment, which reduces the risk and capital invested.
Developers typically phase their subdivision over time, so
that both the developer/landowner partnership and families that
purchase early gain from the appreciation resulting from the
occupation of the project. Developers invest a small amount –
US$300-$700 per lot – in starter infrastructure that
approximates the norms set by government
regulation.
Firms ignore regulations that would raise costs to levels that
would price their product out of their target market segment.
Families then build the structure of their homes and pressure
government for other services – most importantly, piped water –
which generally arrives 10 to 15 years after the initial
development – and paving of roads and schools, which usually
takes longer. Virtually none of these settlements have piped
sewerage – the most costly type of infrastructure. Instead,
residents build unimproved pit latrines, which frequently
contaminate underground water and wells – the main source of
their drinking water.
This modus operandi results in monthly payments
affordable to a wide range of low and moderate-income
households. However, rent-to-own contracts can be highly
problematic. Arrears of three or more months in payment permit
the developer to repossess the lot and sell it to another
family. On making the final payment, some families discover
that the developer/landowner partnership has mortgaged or sold
the land to others, and have problems getting clear legal title
to their lot.
From the perspective of developers, the low investment of
capital in projects has allowed massive production of
progressive subdivisions that has substantially exceeded demand
but, nevertheless, turned a profit. The three largest
developers have produced an average of 10,500 lots per year
compared with annual sales of around 3,000 lots per annum.
Financial analysis of a typical project in one of the most
active current markets (municipality of San Miguel) shows a net
return of 25% to 35% per annum, around the national median
profit rate for private-sector investment.
Progressive subdivisions started in the 1960s, but occurred
outside of national and local law until 1992. In 1992, national
government approved the Law for Urban Development and
Construction and Regulation of Subdivisions (Barraza, 2007;
Souza, 2001). This law created a category called “Subdivision
for Progressive Development” for low-income households, a Social
Register of Real Property, and the Institute Of Liberty and
Progress (model on and on Hernando De Soto’s efforts in Peru of
the same name) in order to legalize informal settlements. In
addition, national government has established a Management Unit
within the National Real Property Registry Office to approve
these plans while municipal governments – which are
constitutionally in charge of land-use – also review progressive
subdivision applications if they have land-use plans. These and
other agencies including the Ministry of the Environment
participate in an inter-institutional committee to review
progressive subdivision applications, which constitutes a
“one-stop shop” (“ventanilla unica”) that coordinates the
approval process for developers.
The progressive subdivision industry and its regulatory
framework in El Salvador have produced marked positive and
negative results:
The regulatory framework adopted in 1992 has succeeded in
converting an illegal industry into a legal one that has rapidly
expanded and now serves 60% of new low-income households.
Government review has helped keep development away from the
most environmentally-hazardous locations. In contrast to the
1960s when illegal subdivisions occurred on hilly lands and
floodplains, regulation has influenced developers to locate new
projects on flat land with suitable soils, although at
increasing distances from city centers.
On the other hand, unoccupied progressive subdivisions now
consume large areas in semirural regions as well as the urban
periphery throughout the country, displacing other land-uses
such as agriculture. Transfer of legal title to households on
payment of the last installment of the rent-to-own contract
continues to be a major issue; a substantial backlog of
progressive subdivisions (mainly from before passage of the
national legislation in 1992)
remain illegal.
The government review process still creates some dilemmas for
developers; in particular, the minimum lot size of 100 square
meters
for urban areas is large compared with other Latin
American countries.
While some regulatory issues remain, the low amount of
funding for new water and sanitation infrastructure is now
clearly the major bottleneck to low and moderate-income
settlement. The water and sanitation system of El Salvador
suffers from weak governance and under-capitalization.
Municipal governments receive a very low share of national tax
revenues in intergovernmental transfers (8%) compared to the
Latin American average (15%), and lack funds for local capital
investment. The lack of funding for infrastructure contributes
to causing the central problem of progressive subdivisions:
although the progressive subdivision system effectively settles
a large share of the low/moderate-income population of the
country, it provides virtually no support for consolidating the
resulting communities over time.
The Low-Income Land Development
Projects of Saiban in Pakistan
Public landownership in Pakistani cities is high, ranging
from 20% to 40% of urban property. The lack of housing finance,
urban development funding, and property tax systems discourages
private real property owners from development and encourages
them to hold raw land for speculation at prices unaffordable to
the majority (World Bank, 2006). These factors throttle legal
land markets and create a perverse dilemma for low-income
housing. Pakistani cities and Karachi (Dowall, 1991), in
particular, have ample vacant land including many unoccupied
formal subdivisions. However, most low and moderate-income
households cannot afford the prices landowners ask for these
lots.
Lacking any legal alternatives, most Pakistani families
either participate in unorganized land invasions or buy lots in
illegal subdivisions, which account for the bulk of urban
settlement since the 1960s as parcels suited to land invasions
have become scarce.
The public sector has an official and an unofficial response
to these severe bottlenecks in housing and land markets, and the
lack of affordable housing. Officially, government agencies
have experimented with a wide range of housing programs
including sites and services, low-cost core units, and slum
upgrading. However, government-produced housing covers a
negligible part of need and demand.
Unofficially, public officers enter into arrangements with
private-sector builders to develop publicly-owned land
informally – i.e. the default mechanism of informal subdivision
that predominates in most emerging-country cities. Clandestine
developers collude with government authorities to use public
land on the urban periphery without formal legal transfer.
The former head of the urban development authority in
Hyderabad, Tasneem Siddiqui, started Saiban, a citizen-sector
organization, in 1987 in order to improve upon and
formalize informal low-income settlement and has continued to
lead the organization. Essentially, Saiban has sought to copy
the informal sector’s affordability, simple procedures, and
rapid delivery, and join them with planned infrastructure
including a sewerage system, a safe environment,
legal title, and access to social services (Siddiqui).
Three projects have created 6,000 affordable titled lots to reach 35,000 low-income
urban residents. A comparable number of lots are in the
pipeline. This total of 12,000 lots exceeds direct government
production but represents less than one year of unmet need (new
household formation) in the Karachi/Hyderabad area.
Saiban’s City
Of God project serves as an example. Saiban acquired a 100-acre
site for a portion of the City of God
project (KKB-3)
from the Malir Development Authority on the outskirts of Karachi.
This nonprofit organization subdivided the land
on a gridiron plan consistent with government zoning
regulations; 20% of the site was allocated for commercial
services and collective functions (schools, medical clinics,
parks etc.) and 30% for roads – much larger shares than
informal subdivisions typically designate for these collective
functions. The remaining 50% was divided into 80 square-yard
residential plots.
The process to apply for and buy a lot is handled on-site and
involves minimal paperwork. Saiban offers a flexible payment
schedule consisting of a downpayment of 20% to 40% (about
US$175) of the total price. Households pay the remaining amount
of US$525 in monthly installments over 100 months. The
resulting payments of US$5.25 per month are affordable even to
the lowest-income households and virtually none drop out of the
process. Saiban keeps ownership of the lot until the last
payment, after which it delivers full legal title to the
families. Saiban has also worked with commercial banks to offer
mortgage finance to those earning US$3 per day and upwards.
In order to discourage speculation, Saiban requires that a
poor family stay at a reception site for up to two weeks to
demonstrate need. On making the downpayment at the end of the
two-week waiting period, the family gains possession but not
title to the plot, which is delivered to the family on payment
of the final installment.
The initial infrastructure is minimal – partly to discourage
speculation – and consists of communal water supply, a soak pit
for sanitation, and public transport from private suppliers.
The remaining infrastructure – including underground sewerage,
piped water, electricity, and paved roads – is extended
incrementally as installment payments are made. Saiban develops
the infrastructure internal to the subdivision including
underground sewer and water pipes, electric poles and wiring,
and internal paved roads funded by the monthly installments from
purchasing households. The relevant government agencies develop
external infrastructure including trunk sewer lines, sewage
treatment plants, bulk water and electricity supply, and access
roads.
In addition, Saiban arranges for a wide variety of other
services. Perhaps most important, Saiban transfers clear title
to the lot when households make the final payment on their land
and ensures public safety in its settlements through agreements
with local police (usually, not to intervene) and others.
Financial analysis shows that a typical Saiban project (City
of God KKB-3 of 2,800 lots) generates a highly positive net
return (US$179,000 more than the total of the purchase cost of
$430,000 plus subsequent development expenses of US$1.32
million). Thus, Saiban’s modus operandi is financially
viable and market-based. However, it depends on the sale of
parcels from government to Saiban. Given the ample amount of
urban land owned by the public sector, scaling up the Saiban
model appears, in principle, a sustainable way to address
low-income land and housing problems in urban Pakistan.
In practice, however, the large financial benefit
to public officials of illegal subdivisions and of government
“sites and services” projects
has substantially slowed
the expansion of Saiban’s production. While the money Saiban
pays to purchase public land goes to the government treasury
department (“exchequer”), illegal subdividers pay under the
table directly to individual government officials. Similarly,
officials receive large commissions from contractors who
over-design and over-estimate the cost of infrastructure for
government sites-and-services projects, also under the table.
As a result, individual officials prefer to sell
public land to clandestine subdividers for their own personal
gain rather than Saiban. The founder and chair of Saiban –
Tasneem Siddiqui
–
states that this organization has sought to purchase an
additional site from the Malir Development Authority to expand
Phase 3 of the City-of-God project near Karachi for the last
three years. This Authority has yet to sell more land to Saiban.
Illegal subdividers, however, have acquired the use of parcels
adjacent to this Saiban project in collusion with the Malir
Development Authority, the Board of Revenue, and the police. In
Islambad, Saiban has yet to get permission to develop land
purchased from private owners four years ago, while illegal
subdivisions proliferate.
Analysis
Table 2 applies the hybrid value-chain
framework
to analyze the progressive subdivisions of El Salvador and Saiban’s
low-income land development projects in Pakistan. Each factor
was rated on a scale of “0” (negligible/never) to “3”
(high/always)
along with a brief explanation. These ratings of individual
factors were used to create average ratings for the settlement
phase, the consolidation phase, and overall. An examination of
these average ratings provides a broad assessment of each case:
The progressive subdivision system of El Salvador scored 2.0
(out of a maximum of 3.0) for settlement, 0.4 for consolidation,
and 2.0 overall. The reasonably good score for settlement
reflects that the progressive subdivision system of El Salvador
allows 60% of new low-income households to acquire a lot in
distant but developable areas. Although this system avoids
extreme environmental hazards, it results in contamination of
groundwater by unimproved pit latrines, the proliferation of
vacant subdivisions, and significant legal and physical
insecurity. The very low score for consolidation reflects these
deficits and the minimal, haphazard support for turning these
settlements into viable communities by extending infrastructure
and for building shelter. Overall, the massive scale and good
affordability compensated for the negative environmental impacts
and the distant location of these projects to achieve an average
rating of 2.0.
Saiban’s low-income land development in Pakistan scored 2.3
for settlement, 1.9 for consolidation, and 2.2 overall. Saiban
– an NGO – does a superior job not only at settlement but also
in supporting consolidation over time of the resulting
communities relative to the for-profit subdivision firms of El
Salvador. The Saiban case demonstrates the potential
value-added of citizen-sector organizations to the progressive
housing process. However, Saiban’s dependence on unreliable
governments for acquiring new parcels (“political
sustainability”) and the resulting limits to scale resulted in
an overall average rating only modestly above that of the
El Salvador case (2.2 compared with 2.0).
Table 2 – Hybrid Value
Chain Analysis of Progressive Subdividions in El Salvador
and Saiban’s Low-Income Land Development Projects in
Pakistan |
Phase |
Step |
|
Progressive Subdivisions
El
Salvador |
Saiban Pakistan |
Settlement |
I. |
Acquisition and occupancy of a lot |
|
|
|
a. |
Physically
occupy lot |
3 |
3 |
|
|
El Salvador
– on signing rent to own contract, households (HHs) can
immediately occupy lot |
|
|
|
|
Pakistan –
after two-week processing/orientation period and making $175
down payment, quick occupancy of lot with minimum of
paperwork |
|
|
|
b. |
Pay for lot |
3 |
3 |
|
|
El Salvador
– $15-$70 monthly payments affordable to great bulk of
low/moderate income HHs |
|
|
|
|
Pakistan –
monthly payments of $5.25 affordable to even poorest HHs |
|
|
|
c. |
Starter
infrastructure
(e.g. communal standpipes/wells or “tanker” water, dirt
roads, electricity) for occupation |
2 |
3 |
|
|
El Salvador
– dirt roads, electricity and, sometimes, communal wells
available on occupation |
|
|
|
|
Pakistan –
dirt roads, tanker water and electricity available on
occupation |
|
|
|
d. |
Construction of an initial makeshift shelter |
0 |
1 |
|
|
El Salvador
– no support |
|
|
|
|
Pakistan –
minimal support |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
II. |
Upgrading property tenure to achieve security of occupation |
|
|
|
a. |
Maintain
physical control of the lot |
2 |
3 |
|
|
El Salvador
– 70% of HHs that sign rent-to-own contract to purchase lots
complete process, 30% unable to maintain monthly payment and
drop out |
|
|
|
|
Pakistan –
virtually 100% of HHs complete process |
|
|
|
b. |
Achieve
secure tenure |
2 |
3 |
|
|
El Salvador
– rent-to-own contracts provide secure tenure for majority
of HHS during payment period, but create legal issues for
minority |
|
|
|
|
Pakistan –
100% of HHs maintain right to their lot during payment
period |
|
|
|
c. |
Full legal
title |
2 |
3 |
|
|
El Salvador
– majority of HHs and projects are able to acquire full
title on completion of payments, but a minority are unable
to |
|
|
|
|
Pakistan –
100% of HHs receive full legal title from Saiban on making
final payment |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Average rating for settlement phase |
2.0 |
2.3 |
|
|
|
|
|
Consolidation |
III. |
Provision of basic infrastructure |
|
|
|
a. |
Upgrading
(e.g. road network, paving, drainage) |
1 |
3 |
|
|
El Salvador
– minimal support provided by government over dacades |
|
|
|
|
Pakistan –
Saiban builds infrastructure internal to subdivision as it
receives HHs payments and arranges for government to build
external infrastructure |
|
|
|
b. |
Adequate
sanitation
(improved pit latrines or sewerage) |
0 |
3 |
|
|
El Salvador
– HHs build their own unimproved pit latrines |
|
|
|
|
Pakistan –
Saiban builds internal sewerate, and government external
sewerage |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
IV. |
Construction of the house structure |
|
|
|
a. |
Improvement
and expansion of unit of owner occupant |
0 |
1 |
|
|
El Salvador
– no support |
|
|
|
|
Pakistan –
minimal support |
|
|
|
b. |
Addition of
accessory units and spaces for relatives and rental income |
0 |
0 |
|
|
El Salvador
– no support |
|
|
|
|
Pakistan –
no support |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
V. |
Finance of steps in progressive housing process |
|
|
|
a. |
Household
savings vehicles |
0 |
0 |
|
|
El Salvador
– no support |
|
|
|
|
Pakistan –
no support |
|
|
|
|
Small
serial short-term credit for – |
|
|
|
b. |
– purchase
of lot |
3 |
3 |
|
|
El Salvador
– development firms finance payment of lot through monthly
installments over 8-12 years |
|
|
|
|
Pakistan –
Saiban finances payment of lot through monthly installments
over 100 months |
|
|
|
c. |
–
infrastructure provision and connection |
0 |
3 |
|
|
El Salvador
– development firms neither finance nor provide
infrastructure/services after provision of minimal starter
infrastructure |
|
|
|
|
Pakistan –
Saiban builds directly infrastructure internal to
subdivision financed by HHs’ downpayment and monthly
installments, and arranges for government to build external
infrastructure |
|
|
|
d. |
– expansion
and improvement of housing structure |
0 |
1 |
|
|
El Salvador
– no support |
|
|
|
|
Pakistan –
Saiban has arranged for a small share of HHs that are
formally employed to get private mortgage loans for house
construction |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
VI. |
Building community institutions and combating insecurity |
|
|
|
a. |
Formation
of neighborhood groups |
0 |
1 |
|
|
El Salvador
– no support |
|
|
|
|
Pakistan –
minimal support |
|
|
|
b. |
Metropolitan, national, and international NGOs support
neighborhood groups |
0 |
3 |
|
|
El Salvador
– no support |
|
|
|
|
Pakistan –
Saiban, an NGO, provides substantial support for settlement
and consolidation |
|
|
|
b. |
Neighborhood groups and/or NGOs partner with government and
the private sector to increase physical and legal security
|
0 |
3 |
|
|
El Salvador
– no support |
|
|
|
|
Pakistan –
Saiban partners with government agencies such as local
police to ensure physical security and guarantees legal
security through delivery of full legal title on final
payment |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Average rating for
consolidation phase |
0.4 |
1.9 |
|
|
|
|
|
Overall characteristics |
|
|
1 |
|
Sustainability |
3 |
2 |
|
a. |
Scale |
|
|
|
|
El Salvador
– serves 60% of new low-income HHs nationwide |
|
|
|
|
Pakistan –
70,000 lots developed or in pipeline far exceed government
affordable-housing production, but serve only a modest
fraction (less than 10%) of new low-income household
formation |
|
|
|
b. |
Financial |
2 |
2 |
|
|
El Salvador
– development firms earn a return of 25% to 35%,
approximately the national average for private sector |
|
|
|
|
Pakistan –
Saiban generates a highly positive net return on each
project, but this depends on purchasing government land at
low prices |
|
|
|
c. |
Political |
3 |
1 |
|
|
El Salvador
– since 1992, a government legal and procedural framework
has developed that results in relatively rapid approval of
projects and appropriate subdivision norms |
|
|
|
|
Pakistan –
Saiban has difficulty in acquiring parcels from government
as needed to supply its project pipeline, resulting in
production substantially below Saiban’s capacity and HHs’
demand |
|
|
|
d. |
Environmental |
1 |
3 |
|
|
El Salvador
– avoids the worst environmental problems that characterized
illegal subdivisions prior to regulation in 1992 (steep
topography, inappropriate soils, location near/on sensitive
or hazardous sites), but without adequate sanitation
resulting in ground- and drinking-water contamination, and
vacant unsold subdivisions occupy large areas, displacing
other land uses |
|
|
|
|
Pakistan –
full infrastructure, especially sewerage, joined with good
site characteristics and adequate location result in
positive environmental impacts |
|
|
2 |
|
Location relative to existing infrastructure, services, and
jobs |
1 |
2 |
|
|
El Salvador
– increasingly distant location often beyond urban periphery
and in semi-rural areas |
|
|
|
|
Pakistan –
on urban periphery |
|
|
3 |
|
Targeting/affordability to low-income households |
2 |
3 |
|
|
El Salvador
– affordable to bulk of low and moderate income HHs |
|
|
|
|
Pakistan –
Saiban income criteria and selection procedures ensure
targeting |
|
|
Average overall rating |
2.0 |
2.2 |
Rating Scale for Level of Project/Product Support to
Progressive Housing Process
0 = negligible/never
1 = low/infrequently
2 = medium/frequently
3 = high/always |
This analysis suggests that citizen-sector organizations can,
indeed, greatly improve outcomes in affordable housing and land
development in emerging countries. However, nonprofits’ dependence
on government for resources – e.g. land parcels, administrative
funding, and project subsidies – often limits their impact to a
fraction of the potential. Thus, partnerships between private firms
and the social sector must compensate local participants for their
role, as do the bottom-of-the-pyramid programs of Cemex and Corona
(Ferguson, 2008).
While these average ratings measure broad performance, the
individual ratings show specific strengths, weaknesses, and ways to
improve affordable-housing projects and products. For example, both
of these cases scored low in Step 4 (Construction of the house) and
step 5 (Finance of steps in progressive housing process). Hence,
both could benefit by incorporating goods and services to streamline
these steps (listed in Column 2 of Table 1). Packages of
high-quality building materials, technical assistance in design and
budgeting, and information to guide home improvement and upgrading
of property tenure could facilitate construction of the house.
Organizing savings groups, creating savings vehicles with a positive
real interest rate, and microloans and supplier credit would help
put in place the missing finance.
Poor scores on Step 6 (Building community institutions and
combating insecurity) indicate that the progressive subdivision
system of El Salvador badly lacks and could benefit tremendously
from involvement of neighborhood groups and NGOs in consolidating
these emerging communities. Such a citizen-sector component could
take various forms. The four leading nationwide development firms
might find that including support for community groups (e.g. land
for/construction of a community center; a small share of households’
payments as ongoing funding for a community association) raises the
sales price and/or volume of their projects sufficiently to
compensate for the cost. The great potential benefits of
citizen-sector organizations in consolidating progressive of the
subdivisions could also justify a public subsidy or a grant from a
donor.
In turn, the analysis shows that Saiban must focus on land
bottlenecks resulting from its dependence on purchasing
publicly-owned parcels at low cost that limit its scale. For
example, including some moderate-income households in Saiban’s
projects would generate a larger net return and the amount that the
organization could pay for land, and allow this NGO to buy more
privately-owned parcels. Working with a larger number of political
jurisdictions could increase the competition among them for Saiban’s
services and result in greater access to government land.
Campaigning for greater transparency in land-use decisions of
government authorities would directly confront a core bottleneck –
the corruption and mismanagement of publicly-owned land that limits
supply. While such a confrontational strategy risks retaliation
from these local officials in the short run, it has the potential to
greatly increase land supply if higher levels of government make
reform a priority.
Conclusion
Hybrid value chains provide a tool to analyze systematically
affordable housing projects and products. El Salvador’s progressive
subdivisions and Saiban’s low-income land development projects in
Pakistan are cases in point. El Salvador has chosen to legalize and
regulate market-based, land-development affordable to low-income
households
that, consequently, has expanded to massive scale.
Although it avoids the worst abuses of clandestine development, El
Salvador’s progressive subdivisions continue to have many
environmental, legal, and economic drawbacks. Government has
developed programs and institutions to deal with some of these
difficulties, but much remains to be done. In this regard, a
crucial next step involves building partnerships with citizen-sector
organizations and firms involved in land development and building
materials supply in order to put in place other elements of the
housing value chain.
Pakistan continues
to allow the worst abuses of illegal subdivisions, which represent
the only settlement option for most low-income household and, thus,
the majority of the urban population of this low-income country. Saiban’s
projects demonstrate a far better market-based approach capable of
massive scale. However, the benefits of illegality – particularly
to local public officials in charge of land-use decisions – hinder
its expansion. Saiban, an NGO, can expand its land development
projects incrementally through applying different
strategies. However, reaching massive scale depends
on reform of land-use decision-making and the administration of the
large amount of land owned by government.
This hybrid value-chain framework can also help orient the
role that government inevitably plays in low-income settlement even
when private-sector organizations (for-profits or nonprofits)
function as developers. In effect, government must act to secure
the inputs (listed in the Column 2 of Table 1) necessary to
streamline the process. Government must galvanize and demonstrate,
when necessary, the feasibility of private-sector initiative as well
as regulate. The means include national legislation, reform of
local subdivision and development review, programs, pilot projects,
partnerships with the private sector, and transparency to combat
corruption.
The conventional approach is for local government to regulate
private development of new urban land. Even in El Salvador, which
has relied mainly on this strategy, this passive limited role has
proved insufficient. Practice and theory now coincide in finding
that government must take a more proactive role to urban land than
simply regulation in order to “enable markets” (Global Urban
Development Magazine, November 2007; Freire et. al., 2007;
Ferguson, 2007; Buckley, 2006). The hybrid
value-chain framework identifies other actions that government must
take
for massive low-income land development:
providing parcels for projects in cases where government owns much of the
stock and land markets are paralyzed (e.g. Pakistan),
promoting household savings vehicles and small housing credits,
streamlining processes for securing intermediate tenure as well as
full legal title, stimulating and working with neighborhood
associations and nonprofit land/housing developers, developing
neighborhood/police partnerships, and – most important of all –
funding basic urban infrastructure and services.
Bruce Ferguson
is a consultant and former Senior Housing and Urban Economist at the
World Bank, and a member of the Advisory Board of Global Urban
Development. He previously served as an Urban Development and
Housing Project Officer at the Inter-American Development Bank, and
has published widely on housing and
urban development in developing countries and the U.S.
Copyright 2008
Citations
Akbar, Tahir. Urban Land and Housing Markets in Sindh,
Pakistan: Evaluation Policy Recommendations. Goldman School
of Public Policy, University Of California at Berkeley. April 30,
2007.
Azfar. A. and A. Rahman. Housing the Urban Poor.
Acumen Fund. April 2004
Ashoka. Housing the Poor by
Engaging the Private and Citizen Sectors: Social Innovations and
“Hybrid Value Chains”. Authors: Stephanie Schmidt with Valeria Budinich.
Arlington, Virginia: Ashoka. 2006.
Ashoka.
“Transforming Urban Markets for the Poor through Collective
Entrepreneurship”
in Global Urban Development Magazine, November 2008.
Barraza, Ernesto.
Analisis sobre el desarrollo de la vivienda progresiva en El
Salvador.
Report prepared for Ashoka under the direction of Bruce
Ferguson.
2007.
Buckley, Robert.
Thirty Years of World Bank Shelter Lending. Washington,
D.C.: World Bank. 2005.
Cohen, Joel E. “Human Population Grows Up” in Scientific
American Vol. 293. No. 3. New York: September, 2005
Dowall, David. “The Karachi Development Authority: Failing
to Get the Prices Right” in Land Economics Vol. 67, No. 4,
pp. 462-471. 1991.
Durand-Lasserve, Alain and Lauren Royston (eds). Holding
Their Ground; Secure Land Tenure for the Urban Poor in Developing
Countries. London: Earthscan Publications. 2002
Ferguson, Bruce. “A
Value Chain Framework for Affordable Housing in Emerging Countries” in Global Urban Development
Magazine, November 2008.
Ferguson, Bruce, “General
Introduction” and “Section Introductions” in Freire, M, R. Lima, D.
Cira, B. Ferguson, C Kessides, J. Mota, and D. Motta, Land and
Urban Policies for Poverty Reduction. World Bank and Brazilian
Institute of Economic and Administrative Studies (IPEA). Washington,
DC.. 2007.
Ferguson, Bruce. "New Approaches to Progressive Housing in Latin
America; a Key to Habitat Programs and Policy", in Habitat
International, London, Pergamon Press, March 2003.
Freire, M, R. Lima, D. Cira, B. Ferguson, C Kessides, J. Mota, and
D. Motta, Land and Urban Policies for Poverty Reduction.
World Bank and Brazilian Institute of Economic and Administrative
Studies (IPEA). Washington, DC. 2007.
Greene, Margharita and Eduardo Rojas. “Incremental construction: a
strategy to facilitate access to housing” in Environment and
Urbanization, London: international Institute for environment
and development. March 2008.
Global Urban Development Magazine. Volume 3, Issue One, World Bank/IPEA
International Urban Research Symposium by Mila Freire. November
2007.
Siddiqui, Tasneem. Presentation on Incremental Housing
Scheme Karachi Pakistan.
Undated.
Souza,
Maria Teresa. Lotificaciones de Desarrollo Progresivo en el
Salvador.
Report prepared for
the Inter-American Development Bank. Washington, DC. 2001.
Stein, Alfredo and
Irene Vance. “The Role of Housing Finance in Addressing the Needs of
the Urban Poor: Lessons from Central America” in Environment and
Urbanization. London: International Institute for Environment
and Development. March, 2008.
Trujillo-Cardenas,
Diana and Roberto Gutierrez. “Citizenship above Consumerism:
Colombia’s Colceramica” in Revista, Fall 2006.
UNCHS (United
Nations Human Settlements Programme), The Challenge of Slums.
London: Earthscan Publications. 2004.
World Bank. Urban Land and Housing Markets in the Punjab,
Pakistan. Draft report. 2006b.